I. Criteria for of Free Elections
A. Inclusiveness: the electorate is large, perhaps "universal"
B. Contestability:
there is (legally) "free entry" of contestants [candidates and/or parties];
all elections are at
least potentially competitive (and most are actually competitive)
C. Fairness
1. to voters: voters are not coerced to vote in a particular way [protected
by secret ballot]
2. to contestants: "reasonable" access to electorate and media [with
much difficulty in specifying what
this means
3. to both: ballots are counted honestly and competently; votes cannot
be bought and sold
[also protected by secret ballot]
D. Governing:
elected official have real governing powers
E. Periodicity:
there is always a next election
II. (Actual or Claimed) Benefits (and Costs) of Free Elections
A. Liberalism
(William Riker, Liberalism Against Populism) or "defensive" benefits:
elected government
are "nice" to citizens (maybe sometimes "too nice" - don't raise taxes, cut
benefits, etc.)
1. precludes "classical tyranny" and general (or "random") oppression
2. problem of "factional (e.g., majority) tyranny" remains
a. absence of highly salient stigmatic divisions in population (especially
one producing a
"majority" faction)
b. multiple crosscutting divisions producing social pluralism (Madison, Federalist
10)
c. Bill of Rights, etc.
d. electoral system / "power sharing"
B. "Populist"
(Riker) policy benefits: elected governments embody "will of [a majority
of] the electorate"
1. elections make government responsive to public opinion
2. elections more or less translate public opinion into policy [Riker (and
others) deny that elections
can have this effect, because public opinion is (in several senses) incoherent]
C. Educative benefits: popular participation, engagement, and education
D. Regular and peaceful leadership transitions
E. Costs
of elections
1. money
2. disruption
3. politicians always "running scared"
4. question of optimal election period (term length)